Fisher, Irving
Irving Fisher
Neoclassical economics &
Post-Keynesian economics |
|
Birth |
February 27, 1867(1867-02-27)
Saugerties, New York |
Death |
April 29, 1947(1947-04-29) (aged 80)
New York City, New York |
Nationality |
United States |
Field |
Mathematical economics |
Alma mater |
Yale University |
Influences |
Gibbs · Sumner |
Influenced |
Friedman · Modigliani |
Contributions |
Fisher equation
Equation of exchange
Price index
Phillips curve
Money illusion
Fisher separation theorem |
Irving Fisher (February 27, 1867 – April 29, 1947) was an American economist, health campaigner, and eugenicist, and one of the earliest American neoclassical economists, though he later rejected the underlying theory of general equilibrium, and his later work on debt deflation is instead considered in the Post-Keynesian school.[1] Although he was perhaps the first celebrity economist, his reputation during his lifetime was irreparably harmed by his sanguine attitude immediately prior to the crash of 1929, and his theory of debt deflation was ignored in favor of the work of John Maynard Keynes.[2] His reputation has since recovered in neoclassical economics since his work was popularized in the late 1950s (Hirshleifer 1958), and more widely due to an increased interest in debt deflation in the Late-2000s recession.[2]
Fisher's work on the quantity theory of money was one of the major influences on the development of Milton Friedman's "monetarism." Friedman called Fisher "the greatest economist the United States has ever produced."[3] Other concepts named after Fisher include the Fisher equation, the Fisher hypothesis, the international Fisher effect, and the Fisher separation theorem.
[edit] Biography
[edit] Early adulthood
Fisher was born in Saugerties, New York. His father was a teacher and Congregational minister, who raised his son to believe he must be a useful member of society. As a child, he had remarkable mathematical ability and a flair for invention. A week after he was admitted to Yale College, his father died at age 53. Irving carried on, however, supporting his mother, brother, and himself, mainly by tutoring. He graduated with a B.A degree in 1888; he was a member of Skull and Bones.
[edit] Career
Fisher's best subject was mathematics, but economics better matched his social concerns. He went on to write a doctoral thesis combining both subjects, on mathematical economics. Irving was granted the first Yale Ph.D. in economics, in 1891. His advisers were the physicist Willard Gibbs and the economist William Graham Sumner. Fisher did not realize at the outset that there was already a substantial European literature on mathematical economics. Nevertheless, his thesis made a contribution European masters such as Francis Edgeworth recognized as first rate. He constructed a wonderful machine of pumps and levers to complement and illustrate his thesis. While his books and articles on economic topics exhibited unusual (for the time) mathematical sophistication, Fisher always wished to bring his analysis to life and to present his theories in a very lucid manner. then studied in Berlin and Paris. From 1890 onward he was at Yale as a tutor, then becoming professor of political economy in 1898, and professor emeritus in 1935.
He edited the Yale Review from 1896 to 1910 and was active in many learned societies, institutes, and welfare organizations. He was a leading proponent of econometrics in its historical development. Among his special interests were temperance, eugenics, public health, and world peace. He won a New York Medical Society prize for the invention of a tent for the treatment of tuberculosis victims. He strongly supported prohibition in the 1920s.
[edit] Theory
Tobin (1985) argues the intellectual breakthroughs that mark the neoclassical revolution in economic analysis occurred in Europe around 1870. The next two decades witnessed lively debates in which the new theory more or less absorbed or was absorbed in the classical tradition that preceded and provoked it.[4]
In the 1890s, according to Joseph A. Schumpeter[5] there emerged
- "A large expanse of common ground and ... a feeling of repose, both of which created, in the superficial observer, an impression of finality -- the finality of a Greek temple that spreads its perfect lines against a cloudless sky." Of course, Tobin argues, the temple was by no means complete. Its building and decoration continue to this day, even while its faithful throngs worship within. American economists were not present at the creation. To a considerable extent they built their own edifice independently, designing some new architecture in the process. They participated actively in the international controversies and syntheses of the period 1870-1914. At least two Americans were prominent builders of the "temple," John Bates Clark and Irving Fisher. They and others brought neoclassical theory into American journals, classrooms, and textbooks, and its analytical tools into the kits of researchers and practitioners. Eventually, for better or worse, their paradigm would dominate economic science in this country."
Fisher's research into basic theory did not touch the great social issues of the day. Monetary economics did and this became the main focus of Fisher’s work. Fisher’s Appreciation and interest was an abstract analysis of the behavior of interest rates when the price level is changing. It emphasized the distinction between real and monetary rates of interest which is fundamental to the modern analysis of inflation. However Fisher believed that investors and savers—people in general—were afflicted in varying degrees by “money illusion”; they could not see past the money to the goods the money could buy. In an ideal world, changes in the price level would have no effect on production or employment. In the actual world with money illusion, inflation (and deflation) did serious harm.
[edit] Later life
Fisher was a prolific writer, producing journalism, as well as technical books and articles, addressing the problems of the First World War, the prosperous 1920s and the depressed 1930s. He died in New York City in 1947, at the age of 80.
[edit] Economic theories
[edit] Money and the price level
Fisher's theory of the price level was the following variant of the quantity theory of money. Let M=stock of money, P=price level, T=amount of transactions carried out using money, and V= the velocity of circulation of money. Fisher then proposed that these variables are interrelated by the Equation of exchange:
- MV=PT.
Later economists replaced the amorphous T with y or "Q", real output, nearly always measured by real GDP.
Fisher was also the first economist to distinguish clearly between real and nominal interest rates:
where r is the real interest rate, i is the nominal interest rate, and inflation is a measure of the increase in the price level. When inflation is sufficiently low, the real interest rate can be approximated as the nominal interest rate minus the expected inflation rate. The resulting equation is known as the Fisher equation in his honor.
For more than forty years, Fisher elaborated his vision of the damaging “dance of the dollar” and devised schemes to “stabilize” money, i.e. to stabilize the price level. He was one of the first to subject macroeconomic data, including the money stock, interest rates, and the price level, to statistical analysis. In the 1920s, he introduced the technique later called distributed lags. In 1973, the Journal of Political Economy reprinted his 1926 paper on the statistical relation between unemployment and inflation, retitling it as "I discovered the Phillips curve". Index numbers played an important role in his monetary theory, and his book The Making of Index Numbers has remained influential down to the present day.
[edit] The theory of interest and capital
While most of Fisher's energy went into social causes and business ventures, and the better part of his scientific effort was devoted to monetary economics, he is best remembered today in neoclassical economics for his theory of interest and capital, studies of an ideal world from which the real world deviated at its peril. His most enduring intellectual work has been his theory of capital, investment, and interest rates, first exposited in his The Nature of Capital and Income (1906) and elaborated on in The Rate of Interest (1907). His 1930 treatise, The Theory of Interest, summed up a lifetime's work on capital, capital budgeting, credit markets, and the determinants of interest rates, including the rate of inflation.
Fisher saw that subjective economic value is not only a function of the amount of goods and services owned or exchanged but also of the moment in time when they are purchased. A good available now has a different value than the same good available at a later date; value has a time as well as a quantity dimension. The relative price of goods available at a future date, in terms of goods sacrificed now, is measured by the interest rate. Fisher made free use of the standard diagrams used to teach undergraduate economics, but labelled the axes "consumption now" and "consumption next period" instead of, e.g., "apples" and "oranges." The resulting theory, one of considerable power and insight, was exposited in considerable detail in The Theory of Interest; for a concise exposition, click here.
This theory, since generalized to the case of K goods and N periods (including the case of infinitely many periods) using the notion of a vector space, has become the canonical theory of capital and interest in contemporary economics; for an exposition see Gravelle and Rees (2004). The nature and scope of this theoretical advance was not fully appreciated, however, until Hirshleifer's (1958) re-exposition, so that Fisher did not live to see this theory's ultimate triumph.
[edit] Debt-Deflation
Further information: Debt deflation
Following the stock market crash of 1929 and the ensuing Great Depression, Fisher developed a theory of economic crises called debt-deflation, which rejected general equilibrium theory and attributed crises to the bursting of a credit bubble.
According to the debt deflation theory, a sequence of effects of the debt bubble bursting occurs:
- Debt liquidation and distress selling.
- Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off.
- A fall in the level of asset prices.
- A still greater fall in the net worth of businesses, precipitating bankruptcies.
- A fall in profits.
- A reduction in output, in trade and in employment.
- Pessimism and loss of confidence.
- Hoarding of money.
- A fall in nominal interest rates and a rise in deflation adjusted interest rates.
This theory was ignored in favor of Keynesian economics, partly due to the damage to Fisher's reputation from his sanguine attitude prior to the crash, but has experienced a revival of mainstream interest since the 1980s, particularly since the Late-2000s recession, and is now a main theory with which he is popularly associated.[2]
[edit] Stock market crash of 1929
The stock market crash of 1929 and the subsequent Great Depression cost Fisher much of his personal wealth and academic reputation. He famously predicted, a few days before the crash, "Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau." Irving Fisher stated on October 21 that the market was "only shaking out of the lunatic fringe" and went on to explain why he felt the prices still had not caught up with their real value and should go much higher. On Wednesday, October 23, he announced in a banker’s meeting “security values in most instances were not inflated.” For months after the Crash, he continued to assure investors that a recovery was just around the corner. Once the Great Depression was in full force, he did warn that the ongoing drastic deflation was the cause of the disastrous cascading insolvencies then plaguing the American economy because deflation increased the real value of debts fixed in dollar terms. Fisher was so discredited by his 1929 pronouncements and by the failure of a firm he had started that few people took notice of his "debt-deflation" analysis of the Depression. People instead eagerly turned to the ideas of Keynes. Fisher's debt-deflation scenario has made something of a comeback since 1980 or so.
[edit] Personal ideals
The lay public perhaps knew Fisher best as a health campaigner and eugenicist. In 1898 he found that he had tuberculosis, the disease that killed his father. After three years in sanatoria, Fisher returned to work with even greater energy and with a second vocation as a health campaigner. He advocated vegetarianism, avoiding red meat, and exercise, writing How to Live: Rules for Healthful Living Based on Modern Science, a USA best seller.
In 1912 he also became a member of the scientific advisory to the Eugenics Record Office and served as the secretary of the American Eugenics Society.
Fisher was also a strong believer in the now-ridiculed "focal sepsis" theory of physician Henry Cotton, who believed that mental illness was attributable to infectious material residing in the roots of the teeth, recesses in the bowels, and other places in the human body, and that surgical removal of this infectious material would cure the patient's mental disorder. Fisher believed in these theories so thoroughly that when his daughter Margaret Fisher was diagnosed with schizophrenia, Fisher had numerous sections of her bowel and colon removed at Dr. Cotton's hospital, eventually resulting in his daughter's death.[6]
Fisher was also an ardent supporter of the Prohibition of alcohol in the United States, and wrote three short books arguing that Prohibition was justified on the grounds of both public health and hygiene, as well as economic productivity and efficiency, and should therefore be strictly enforced by the United States government.[7]
[edit] See also
- A Program for Monetary Reform (1939)
- Marginalism
[edit] Selected publications
Fisher, Irving Norton, 1961. A Bibliography of the Writings of Irving Fisher (1961). Compiled by Fisher's son; contains 2425 entries.
- Primary
- 1892. Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices. Scroll to chapter links.
- 1896. Appreciation and Interest. Link.
- 1906. The Nature of Capital and Income. Scroll to chapter links.
- 1907. The Rate of Interest. Extracts from Preface and Appendix to ch. VII.
- 1910, 1914. Introduction to Economic Science. Section links.
- 1911a, 1922, 2nd ed. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit, Interest, and Crises. Scroll to chapter links from Library of Economics and Liberty (LE&L).
- 1911b, 1913. Elementary Principles of Economics. Scroll to chapter links.
- 1915. How to Live: Rules for Healthful Living Based on Modern Science (with Eugene Lyon Fisk). Link.
- 1918, "Is 'Utility' the Most Suitable Term for the Concept It is Used to Denote?" American Economic Review, p[p. 335]-37. Reprint.
- 1921a. "Dollar Stabilization," Encyclopædia Britannica 12th ed.. XXX, pp. 852–853. Reprint page links from LE&L.
- 1921b, The Best Form of Index Number, American Statistical Association Quarterly. 17(133), p p. 533-537.
- 1922. The Making of Index Numbers: A Study of Their Varieties, Tests, and Reliability. Scroll to chapter links,
- 1923, "The Business Cycle Largely a 'Dance of the Dollar'," Journal of the American Association, 18, pp. 1024–28.
- 1926, "A Statistical Relation between Unemployment and Price Changes," International Labour Review, 13(6), p p. 785-92. Reprinted as 1973, "I Discovered the Phillips Curve: A Statistical Relation between Unemployment and Price Changes'," Journal of Political Economy, 81(2, Part 1), p p. 496-502.
- 1927, "A Statistical Method for Measuring 'Marginal Utility' and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax" in Economic Essays Contributed in Honor of John Bates Clark .
- 1928, The Money Illusion, New York: Adelphi Company. Scroll to chapter-preview links.
- 1930a. The Stock Market Crash and After.
- 1930b. The Theory of Interest. Chapter I. Chapter links, each numbered by paragraph via LE&L.
- 1932. Booms and Depressions: Some First Principles. Description and links (press +) via Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis.
- 1933a. "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions," Econometrica, 1(4), pp. 337-357 (press +) from FRBSL.
- 1933b. Stamp Scrip. Chapter links.
- 1935. 100% Money.
- 1996. The Works of Irving Fisher. edited by William J. Barber et al. 14 volumes London : Pickering & Chatto.
- Fisher, Irving. (1892). Mathematical Investigations
[edit] References and further reading
- Allen, Robert Loring. Irving Fisher: A Biography (1993) online excerpt
- Dimand, Robert W. (2003). "Irving Fisher on the International Transmission of Booms and Depressions through Monetary Standards." Journal of Money, Credit & Banking. Vol: 35#1 pp 49+. online edition
- Dimand, Robert W. (1993)."The Dance of the Dollar: Irving Fisher's Monetary Theory of Economic Fluctuations," History of Economics Review 20:161-172.
- Dimand, Robert W. (1994)."Irving Fisher's Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions," Review of Social Economy 52:92-107
- Dimand, Robert W. (1998). "The Fall and Rise of Irving Fisher's Macroeconomics," Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20:191-201.
- Dimand, Robert W., and Geanakoplos, John. 2005. "Celebrating Irving Fisher: The Legacy of a Great Economist" American Journal of Economics & Sociology, Jan 2005, Vol. 64 Issue 1, pp 3-18
- Dorfman, Joseph. (1958) The Economic Mind in American Civilization vol 3.
- Fellner, William, ed. (1967). Ten Economic Studies in the Tradition of Irving Fisher
- Fisher, Irving Norton, 1956. My Father Irving Fisher.
- Gravelle, H., and Rees, R., 2004. Microeconomics, 3rd ed. Pearson Education. Chpt. 11.
- Jack Hirshleifer, 1958, "The Theory of Optimal Investment Decisions," Journal of Political Economy 66: 329-352.
- Sasuly, Max, 1947, "Irving Fisher and Social Science," Econometrica 15: 255-78.
- Joseph Schumpeter, 1951. Ten Great Economists: 222-38.
- Joseph Schumpeter. 1954 A History of Economic Analysis (1954)
- Thaler, Richard, 1999, "Irving Fisher: Behavioral Economist," American Economic Review.
- Tobin, James, 1987, "Fisher, Irving," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Vol. 2: 369-76. Reprinted in American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Jan, 2005, 17 pages.
- Tobin, James, 1985 "Neoclassical Theory in America: J. B. Clark and Fisher" American Economic Review (Dec 1985) vol 75#6 pp 28-38in JSTOR
[edit] Notes
- Debtwatch No. 42: The economic case against Bernanke, January 24th, 2010, Steve Keen
- ^ a b c Out of Keynes's shadow, The Economist, Feb 12th 2009
- Milton Friedman, Money Mischief: Episodes in Monetary History, Houghton Mifflin Harcourt (1994) p. 37. ISBN 0-15-661930-X
- James Tobin, "Neoclassical Theory in America: J. B. Clark and Fisher" American Economic Review (Dec 1985) vol 75#6 pp 28-38
- Schumpeter, A History of Economic Analysis (1954), p. 754
- Madhouse: A Tragic Tale of Megalomania and Modern Medicine, Andrew Scull, Yale University Press, 2005
- Irving Fisher: Prohibition at Its Worst (New York: Macmillan, 1926); Prohibition Still at Its Worst (New York: Alcohol Information Committee, 1928); The Noble Experiment (New York: Alcohol Information Committee, 1930).
- Library of Economics and Liberty
[edit] External links
Neoclassical economists |
|
William Stanley Jevons · Francis Ysidro Edgeworth · Alfred Marshall · John Bates Clark · Irving Fisher · Kenneth Arrow · Hirofumi Uzawa · Axel Leijonhufvud · Martin Feldstein · Fumio Hayashi
|
|
Walrasian economics |
Maurice Allais · Gérard Debreu · Edmond Malinvaud · Jacques Drèze · Jean-Michel Grandmont · Guy Laroque · Jean-Pascal Benassy · Yves Younes
|
|
New classical macroeconomics |
Robert Lucas, Jr. · Thomas J. Sargent · Neil Wallace · Robert Barro · Edward C. Prescott · Finn E. Kydland · Bennett McCallum · Christopher A. Sims
|
|
Persondata |
Name |
Fisher, Irving |
Alternative names |
|
Short description |
|
Date of birth |
February 27, 1867 |
Place of birth |
|
Date of death |
April 29, 1947 |
Place of death |
|